Abstract
It has been known for decades that in a given year and in a given country, with the rise in lifetime income, life expectancy also rises. The difference between the richest and the poorest stratas' life expectancies is called the longevity gap. Recently, as the gap has generally been growing, it has received more and more attention. The issue is important in itself, but it has also an obvious impact on redistribution in the pension system: the greater the longevity gap, the greater is the redistribution from the low benefit pensioners to the high benefit ones in a given pension system. Econometrically estimating the life expectancy-income function may help the analysis. In our short study, first we give a simple estimation, and then we show the influence of the estimate on the redistribution.
1 Introduction
While the secular rise of average life expectancy has received much attention, its heterogeneity with respect to lifetime-income has only been discovered lately. The latter phenomenon has been referred to as longevity gap. This can be quantified as the difference between the life expectancy (LE) of the richest and the poorest parts of the population (longevity gap).
For example, using the data of the Social Security Administration of the USA, Chetty et al. (2016) estimated this relation for the total USA population between 2001 and 2014.1 One of their most important observations (see their Figure 2) is that among those males who survived 65, the richest 1% lives 15 years longer than the poorest percentile; for females, this gap is equal to 10 years. In that paper a table supplements their Figure, providing the relevant numbers for percentiles 20, 40, 60 and 80% without presenting the average number of longevity years for the whole population. Our related calculations witnessing this heterogeneity are displayed in Table 1, Figures 1 and 2 of the present paper. The digital version of the cited paper contains the full data set.2 The definition and the calculation of the life expectancy at a given age are quite challenging issues but we skip them here.
The statistical indicators of the data set 2001–2014, US
Variables | Minimum | Average | Maximum | Standard deviation |
Female LE65 (yr) | 78.53 | 84.93 | 88.91 | 2.17 |
Female relative income | 0.0044 | 0.97 | 20.29 | 2.03 |
Male LE65 (yr) | 72.37 | 81.17 | 87.19 | 3.32 |
Male relative income | 0.0036 | 1.03 | 19.68 | 2.10 |
Source: Chetty et al. (2016).
The classical approach has neglected the existence of the gap and confined its attention to the issue on the dependence of the benefit-earning-ratio on the household earning: a priori progressivity. For example, in the US Social Security, the normal monthly pension benefit of a person is an increasing concave piecewise linear function of his/her primary monthly income.3 Recently the impact of longevity gap on a posteriori redistribution in the pension system has also received increasing attention – the gap decreases the progressivity discussed in the classical approach. The greater the gap, the greater is the redistribution from the low-paid to the high-paid. In fact, the so-called proportional benefits are not proportional at all (Liebmann 2002; Whitehouse – Zaidi 2008; Holzmann et al. 2020.)
The redistribution in the pension system can be measured by the relative standard deviation of the lifetime net contribution balances across the population or aggregates of population. (Note that the standard deviation does not distinguish between the positive and negative signs of the balance, only its absolute value matters. Therefore, the indicator shows the same way transfer from the poor to the rich and vice versa.) To measure redistribution, it is more appropriate to use absolute or relative incomes than percentile incomes that are available (Chetty et al. 2016). Holzmann et al. (2019: 323–324 and Figure 14.7) estimated the relation of life expectancy – lifetime income in quadratic and logarithmic forms. Their final conclusion: If the estimation of redistribution is quite good for the largely heterogeneous US population, where the longevity gap is quite large and ex ante redistribution is quite strong, the approximation is even better in other, less heterogeneous countries, where the longevity gap is smaller and ex ante redistribution is weaker.4
In certain empirical but especially in theoretical models, it can be more suitable to use econometrically estimated functions rather than empirical data. For example, in their well-calibrated theoretical model, Sheshinski – Caliendo (2021) determined the decrease in the genuine progressivity of the US Social Security for subsequent year-groups by econometric estimations. We also proceed in this direction. Our main result is as follows: if the relation of life expectancy – lifetime income is well estimated, then the redistribution in the pension system is also correctly estimated.5
In our research we follow the method of Sheshinski – Caliendo (2021) (also Chapter 14 of Simonovts 2018) but use the data of Chetty et al. (2016). To eliminate two genders, we add up the male and female balances. The female – male distinction could be crucial because females live much longer, they earn much less, and they frequently enjoy widow's pensions. Its inclusion, however, would be immature at this stage.
We find that the classical assumption of constant life expectancy is unacceptable, but the power function estimate is acceptable. In addition, in another paper, Simonovits (2021) mathematically analyses the connection of the longevity gap and redistribution.6
Though it is a toy model, it has some policy relevance: the existence of sizable ex post redistribution in a priori neutral pension system weakens the case for nonfinancial defined contribution (NDC) public pensions (Holzmann et al. 2019).
The structure of the remainder of the paper is as follows. Section 2 presents the data in Chetty et al. (2016) and estimates the power-function form of the life expectancy-lifetime income relation. Section 3 displays the simplest version of the impact of these estimations on the redistribution. Section 4 draws the conclusions. An Appendix contains the complementary detailed statistics of our estimations.
2 Data and estimations
The descriptive statistical indicators of the data set are given in Table 1 above. Working with households, male and female incomes hardly differ.
We have already discussed the longevity gap, spanning between male and female life-expectancies of higher- and lower-paid strata, respectively, but we have only seen the tremendous lifetime income differences. The estimated parameter values of the life expectancy-income connection is displayed in Table 2, with the power function. Because we calculate across percentiles, the number of elements in the samples is, n = 100. We take the average values for years 2001–2014. In the Appendix, we present the detailed results of the calculations, while here we show only the main results.
Power-function estimates of the lifetime – relative income connection, 2001–2014
Coefficients | Females | Males | ||||
Estimates | SD | R2 | Estimates | SD | R2 | |
0.92 | 0.90 | |||||
log L0i | 4.445 | 0.001 | 4.415 | 0.0017 | ||
ai | 0.022 | 0.0015 | 0.034 | 0.0027 |
In Table 2 we find that: a) R2 is above 0.9; b) the power coefficients are equal to 0.022 (0.034), i.e., a rise of 1% relative income would raise life expectancy by 0.022 (0.034) % for females (males).
Figures 1 and 2 show the power function estimation as well as the actual data for female and male populations, respectively.7 How does the (full) life expectancy at 65 depend on the relative lifetime incomes? Considering that only relative incomes of percentiles 99 and 100 are higher than 4, the estimations are satisfactory.
3 Redistribution in the pension system
It is an important question how the actual and the estimated longevity gaps influence the redistribution in the pension systems. We illustrate it in a simplest model. We assume away some important dimensions of the US and other public pension systems.
We calculate the degree of redistribution for three specifications for the single period of 2001–2014: (i) classical specification: L(y) = EL (i.e., constant life expectancy); (ii) power function specification (1) or equivalently (5) and (iii) the actual data.
Table 3 shows the results of the three specifications for α = 1/2, including the classic case above, the two other specifications need computer, the results are displayed in rows 2 and 3.
Life expectancy relative earnings specifications, contribution rates and standard deviation of the balances
Life expectancy Relative earnings LF(yF), LM(yM) | Balanced contribution rate τ* | Standard deviation of balances σz*/Ew |
Constant (classic) | 0.180 | 0.078 |
Power function | 0.178 | 0.096 |
Actual | 0.176 | 0.130 |
Table 3 reveals that the balanced contribution rate moderately rises with the perfection of the estimation: from 0.18 to 0.178 and 0.176. The relative standard deviation of the estimated and of the actual balances jumps from 0.078 to 0.096, and 0.130. The underlying cause of the latter is that if the life expectancies were independent of the incomes, then a 50–50% mix of proportional and basic pensions would achieve a significant redistribution, the relative standard deviation of the balances would be equal to 0.078. With the existence of the gap, however, this redistribution further increases: the finer the estimation of Li(yi) and consequently ui(yi), the more it increases.
A fuller model would not stop here. There we should take into account the impact of redistribution on the workers' labour supply. In addition, we should consider the welfare effects of the pension system, i.e., how the private savings modify the impact of the contribution and the benefits on young- and old-age consumption and the impact of the redistribution on life expectancy (Miglino et al. 2023). This is beyond the scope of the present paper.
4 Conclusions
Using the US data set of Chetty et al. (2016), our short paper econometrically estimated the dependence of male and female life expectancy on relative lifetime income for the percentiles of the population. Replacing the classical approach of constant life expectancy, we have also used the power function estimation, and this way we have obtained a satisfactory estimation. Using a unisex data set and a simple pension model, we compared the balanced contribution rates and the standard deviations of the lifetime balances for three approaches. We have found that the classical approach is unacceptable, while the power-function approach is acceptable. The existence of the longevity gap increases a posteriori redistribution.
During the calculations, we neglected a number of complications: we skipped over the differences between lifetime earnings and total lifetime incomes; we replaced 15 cohorts by a unified group; we replaced heterogeneous contribution lengths and retirement ages by single values. We streamlined the US benefit rules (neglecting the maximization of the number of assessed years of contribution, the piecewise linearity of the benefit rule and the actuarial reduction/increase due to early/late retirement). In any further work, these simplifications must be eliminated.
Acknowledgements
This research was supported by NKF 129078. We express our debt to Anikó Bíró, Zsombor Cseres-Gergely, Gábor Kőrösi, Gábor Tusnády and anonymous referees of earlier versions.
References
Bíró, A. – Hajdu, T. – Kertesi, G. – Prinz, D. (2021): Life Expectancy Inequalities in Hungary over 25 Years: The Role of Avoidable Deaths. Population Studies. Journal of Demography, 75(3): 443–455.
Chetty, R. – Stepner, M. – Abraham, S. – Lin, S. – Scuderi, B. – Turner, N. – Bergeron, A. – Cutler, D. (2016): The Association between Income and Life Expectancy in the United States, 2001–2014. Journal of the American Medical Association, 315(16): 1750–1766.
Haan, P. – Kemptner, D. – Lüthen, H. (2020): The Rising Longevity Gap by Lifetime Earnings – Distributional Implications for the Pension System. The Journal of the Economics of Ageing, No. 17.
Holzmann, R. – Alonso-García, J. – Labit-Hardy, H. – Villegas, A. M. (2019): NDC Schemes and Heterogeneity in Longevity: Proposals for Redesign. Social Protection and Jobs Discussion Paper, No. 1913, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Holzmann, R. – Palmer, E. – Palacios, R. – Robalino, D. (2020) (eds): Progress and Challenges of Nonfinancial Defined Contribution Schemes. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Liebmann, J. B. (2002): Redistribution in the Current U.S. Social Security System. In: Feldstein, M. – Liebmann, J. B. (eds): The Distributional Aspects of Social Security and Social Security Reform. Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp.: 11–48.
Knell, M. (2018): Increasing Life Expectancy and NDC Pension Systems. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance, 17(2): 170–199.
Miglino, E. – Navarrete, N. H. – Navarrete, H. G. – Navarrete, H. P. (2023): Health Effects of Increasing Income for the Elderly: Evidence from a Chilean Pension Program. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 15(1): 370–393.
OECD (2011): Pensions at a Glance 2011: Retirement – Income Systems in OECD and G20 Countries. Paris.
Sanchez-Romero, M. – Lee, R. D. – Prskawetz, A. (2020): Redistributive Effects of Different Pension Systems when Longevity Varies by Socioeconomic Status. The Journal of the Economics of Ageing, Vol. 17.
Sanchez-Romero, M. – Schuster, P. – Prskawetz, A. (2021): Redistributive Effects of Pension Reforms: Who Are the Winners and Losers? ECON WPS - Working Papers in Economic Theory and Policy, No. 06/2021, Institute of Statistics and Mathematical Methods in Economics, Research Unit in Economics, Vienna.
Sheshinski, E. – Caliendo, F. N. (2021): Social Security and the Increasing Longevity Gap. Journal of Theoretical Public Economics, 23(1): 29–52.
Simonovits, A. (2018): Simple Models of Income Redistribution. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.
Simonovits, A. (2021): Longevity Gap and Pensions: A Minimal Model. Centre for Economic and Regional Studies, Hungarian Academy of Sciences, Institute of Economics Working Paper, No. 2021/30.
Whitehouse, E. – Zaidi, A. (2008): Socioeconomic Differences in Mortality: Implications for Pension Policy. OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 71, Paris.
Appendix
Statistical additions
Dependent variable: ln(LE65) | Females | Males |
Estimated | Estimated | |
parameters | parameters | |
ln(y/y*) | 0.022*** | 0.034*** |
st.error | 0.0015 | 0.0027 |
conf. interv. | 0.019–0.025 | 0.028–0.039 |
constant | 4.455*** | 4.415*** |
st.error | 0.0010 | 0.0017 |
conf. interv. | 4.453–4.458 | 4.417–4.418 |
aR2 | 0.925 | 0.90 |
RMSE | 0.0071 | 0.013 |
F | F(1, 98) = 210.8 | F(1, 98) = 152.9 |
Number of observations | 100 | 100 |
Note: RMSE: Root Mean Square Error.
Significance level: *** <1, ** <5, and *< 10%.
https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC4866586/. Haan et al. (2020) observed similar phenomena on the German cohorts.
Bíró et al. (2021) documented the same gap on Hungarian data.
For a related concept of progressivity index of pensions, see OECD 2011 (136–137). https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/docserver/pension_glance-2011-24-en.pdf?expires=1637505284&id=id&accname=guest&checksum=A4E0A84468675C29607DEF5254C2586B.
Sanchez-Romero et al. (2020, 2021) analysed the feedback of pension reforms on the life expectancies in a model calibrated by Austrian data. They used the internal rate of return rather than lifetime balance to compare the treatment of various strata.
To avoid any misunderstanding, we emphasise that in our paper, the econometric estimation is used only for analytical purposes.
It is worth mentioning that Knell (2018) studied a related but not identical problem: the impact of increasing life expectancy on national defined contribution (NDC) pension systems.
Data for percentile 100 are not indicated in the figures.
The impact of the first parameter was studied in Simonovits (2021) in detail.
This approach was implicitly suggested by one of the referees.